Thursday, December 08, 2011

My letter to the House Budget Committee

Please share these comments that I made on The Fiscal Times article about your announcement with the majority (who does not take e-mail).


http://www.thefiscaltimes.com/Articles/2011/12/07/Ryans-New-Budget-Proposals-Zero-Chance-of-Passing.aspx#page1

(You) are almost there and not grandstanding. Shifting to Joint Budget Resolution on a biennial basis is a good idea - and changing the budget process as part of an eventual tax and budget deal is not unheard of. Automatic expenditure is also a good idea if there is no budget at the end of the year - which a Joint Budget Resolution makes possible.

I would limit the President's initial budget submission for the two year budget to Joint Budget Solution totals only. After the JBR passes, the White House would submit detailed appropriation numbers, entitlement and tax law changes, major regulatory actions (for amendment) and a current services budget showing how current law fits into the JBR totals. If appropriations are not passed or are vetoed, the JBR current services numbers become law automatically, forcing the appropriations committee to work with the Administration and get its work done on time or resort to supplemental appropriations after the fiscal year starts.

P.S. I would also consider setting up a Joint Budget Committee - however the failure of the Joint Select Committee to come up with a package mitigages against that.

Wednesday, December 07, 2011

Hearing: Drug Shortages: Why They Happen and What They Mean

Comments for the Record
United States Senate Committee on Finance
Hearing: Drug Shortages: Why They Happen and What They Mean
December 7, 2011, 10:00 AM
215 Dirksen Senate Office Building

by Michael G. Bindner
The Center for Fiscal Equity


Chairman Baucus and Ranking Member Hatch, thank you for the opportunity to address this topic. Our response will be within the context of our four part tax proposal, which includes a VAT to fund discretionary spending, payroll taxes to fund Old Age and Survivors Insurance, an income surtax on higher income individuals and families to fund overseas military deployments, debt reduction and net interest and a Net Business Receipts Tax to fund social spending, including health. We will not duplicate witness statements that lay out the problem, except to assert that the largest driver of drug shortages is an uneven relationship between drug manufacturers and consumers.

One feature of the NBRT is that it allows employers to fund health plans for workers and retirees or provide direct services in lieu of paying taxes so that individual benefits can be funded. Of course, in a single payer or public option environment, the government would be the 800 pound gorilla driving negotiations with drug companies to guarantee the availability of drugs and disbarring any companies that engage in price gouging.

One feature of the NBRT, either with single-payer or without it, is that employers could be given an incentive to offer alternative care arrangements, either a better plan than is available under single-payer or direct care with staff physicians, contract facilities and contract specialists for employees and even retirees as an offset to a portion of the NBRT payment. This feature provides an incentive for significant cost savings.

Employers who fund catastrophic care or operate nursing care facilities would get an even higher benefit, with the proviso that any care so provided be superior to the care available through Medicaid.

Making employers responsible for most costs and for all cost savings allows them to use some market power to get both lower prices for drugs and the ability to demand that lower cost drugs be available – leverage that individuals just don’t have.

This proposal is probably the most promising way to arrest health care costs from their current upward spiral – as employers who would be financially responsible for this care through taxes would have a real incentive to limit spending in a way that individual taxpayers simply do not have the means or incentive to exercise.

While not all employers would participate, those who do would dramatically alter the market. In addition, a kind of beneficiary exchange could be established so that participating employers might trade credits for the funding of former employees who retired elsewhere, so that no one must pay unduly for the medical costs of workers who spent the majority of their careers in the service of other employers.

Thank you for the opportunity to address the committee. We are, of course, available for direct testimony or to answer questions by members and staff.

Tuesday, December 06, 2011

Tax Reform and the Tax Treatment of Financial Products

Comments for the Record


United States Senate Committee on Finance
United States House Committee on Ways and Means


Tax Reform and the Tax Treatment of Financial Products
Tuesday, December 6, 2011, 10:00 AM
HVC-210 Capitol Visitor Center
By Michael G. Bindner
Center for Fiscal Equity


Chairmen Baucus and Camp, thank you for the opportunity to submit comments for the record on this topic. We will leave it to the invited witnesses to describe how current tax law treats financial products and will confine ourselves how such products might work under our tax and entitlement reform proposals. As you know, the Center for Fiscal Equity has a four part proposal for long term tax and health care reform. The key elements are

  • a Value Added Tax (VAT) that everyone pays, except exporters,
  • a VAT-like Net Business Receipts Tax (NBRT) that is paid by employers but, because it has offsets for providing health care, education benefits and family support, does not show up on the receipt and is not avoidable at the border,
  • a payroll tax to for Old Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) (unless, of course, we move from an income based contribution to an equal contribution for all seniors), and
  • an income and inheritance surtax on high income individuals so that in the short term they are not paying less of a tax burden because they are more likely to save than spend – and thus avoid the VAT and indirect payment of the NBRT.

There is a great deal of literature on the tax treatment of financial operations under a VAT regime. We suggest that, should you wish to consider our proposal more fully, you invite these experts to testify. Some of these issues are particularly complex and their treatment would exceed the space allowed for comments.

From an investor point of view, how the financial instrument is treated in the tax code has less of an impact than the existence of a Value Added Tax and VAT-like Net Business Receipts Tax. Regardless of how the financial product is structured, once the cash is to be spent at the household level, taxes will be paid. This fact will likely diminish the demand for certain financial products, since tax avoidance will only go so far – particularly since we propose an income and inheritance income surtax floor of $50,000 for individuals and $100,000 for joint filers and qualifying widow(er)s.

The payroll tax provision also has no impact on the taxation of financial instruments. Of course, if the payroll tax component were used to facilitate a transition to union and employee managed personal retirement accounts holding insured employer voting stock, rather than broker managed Wall Street index funds, the need for and availability of financial products would diminish and eventually disappear as private investment provided more and more of the capital investment needs of industry. Additionally, employee-owned firms are more likely to offer credit products to their employee-owners in the areas of insurance, mortgages, consumer credit and retirement. Complex financial products to fulfill these functions will also decline in such a scenario.

We should probably not bring this fact up, as the army who get rich offering such products is likely to mount formidable resistance should our proposal ever be considered. We expect that this is why none of our comments have been given any attention by either revenue committee. Considering the hunger to restrict such paper wealth that is arising among the self-styled 99%, we don’t expect you will be able to ignore these ideas forever.

The tax benefits assigned to financial products may or may not be continued in the tax reform we propose, since our intent was to include very few deductions for our high income surtax. Whether this goal is accomplished is, of course, entirely up to the congressional revenue committees. Our hope is that you will close most loopholes so that high income taxpayers no longer spend perfectly good money to game the system. In the end, they would only be competing with each other and because interest on the debt and debt repayment would be funded by the surtax, any savings they get personally will simply add up to a tax burden on their children, rather than the next generation as a whole. Indeed, taxation at much higher rates would likely be demanded by such taxpayers once this fact became clear.

Thank you again for the opportunity to present our comments. We are always available to discuss them further with members, staff and the general public.

Friday, December 02, 2011

Securing the Future of the Social Security Disability Insurance Program

Comments for the Record
House Ways and Means Committee
Subcommittee on Social Security
Hearing on Securing the Future of the Social Security Disability Insurance Program
Friday, December 2, 2011, 9:00 AM

by Michael Bindner
The Center for Fiscal Equity


Chairman Johnson and Ranking Member Becerra, thank you for the opportunity to submit my comments on this topic. We will leave it to the invited witnesses to describe the history of the program, limiting our comments to the adequacy of the benefits provided under the program and how these may be overcome in the context of our proposals for tax and entitlement reform.

There are three outstanding features of the program that need attention: difficulty of entrance, adequacy of benefits and difficulty of exit.

The difficulty of getting on the benefit roles is legendary. It is so blatant that state governments have programs to provide incomes to applicants under the heading of general welfare benefits while they are appealing an initial denial of benefits. A whole field of disability law has evolved to help people get the benefits to which they are entitled, at a high cost to taxpayers in terms of legal fees when the applicant is finally successful. Clearly, more discretion to accept claims should be granted to benefits examiners so that this step is not necessary for routine cases. Only difficult cases should be subject to advanced review. It should not be an expected step in the application process.

The second concern is the adequacy of benefits. Most workers who need this type of assistance have been engaged in physical work, which often does not pay well outside the union setting. With the decline in union membership, this is most physical labor. Other beneficiaries need benefits due to physical, mental or emotional difficulties – from Down’s Syndrome to alcoholism and mental illness – which often depress earning capability. As a consequence, income based benefits tend to be lower than those for the average worker.

Both the circumstances of the disability and the rules limiting additional income further depress income by program participants, making them reliant on still more government services, such as public housing, SNAP and Medicare.

The difficulty in going back on the benefit rolls once one exits for a time also lead most beneficiaries to resist any attempt at rehabilitation or training that might, for a time, allow them to exit the program. If re-entry were easier due to changes in circumstances, more beneficiaries would take advantage of training and work opportunities.

Fixing the application procedures and adequately training staff are outside the scope of our recommendations, as vital as these steps are. We will offer the following hint on where to look. We are quite sure that the staff on the ground would be a good source of solutions to these problems, if only they were empowered to implement them.

Our proposed solutions have more to do with how the program should be financed, how benefits are calculated, what other benefits should be available to participants and how to enable participants to return to the workforce – if only for a time. These solutions exist inside our comprehensive solutions for tax and entitlement reform. As you may know, the Center for Fiscal Equity suggests a four part tax reform, which form the basis of our analysis. The key elements are:

• a Value Added Tax (VAT) that everyone pays, except exporters,
• a VAT-like Net Business Receipts Tax (NBRT) that is paid by employers but, because it has offsets for providing health care, education benefits and family support, does not show up on the receipt and is not avoidable at the border,
• a payroll tax to for Old Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) (unless, of course, we move from an income based contribution to an equal contribution for all seniors), and
• an income and inheritance surtax on high income individuals so that in the short term they are not paying less of a tax burden because they are more likely to save than spend – and thus avoid the VAT and indirect payment of the NBRT.
We will deal with how each of these proposals relates to the circumstances of program participant.

In the event a VAT is adopted, we propose that program participants receive a one time cost of living adjustment (COLA) at the VAT rate in the year the VAT takes effect, with further adjustments in any year the VAT rate increases. This is also applicable if our proposals for a regional VAT are enacted as amendments to the United States Constitution.

We propose that Disability Insurance payroll taxes be repealed, with funding coming from our proposed Net Business Receipts Tax. Repealing this tax provides a justification for decoupling the benefit level from past income. An income based benefit should be replaced with a standard benefit. During the application phase, instead of forcing participants onto state welfare rolls, the last employer would pay the standard benefit – which should be at least the minimum wage for a full time worker, if not higher – with this payment offsetting the employers NBRT liability and, if necessary, its VAT collections.

If the employee has dependent children, each child will also receive the refundable expanded Child Tax Credit with their benefits (currently estimated at $52o per child per month). Please note that we propose elsewhere that the minimum wage be increased to $12 an hour so that no one is paid primarily through the Child Tax Credit and that both the minimum wage and the credit be automatically adjusted for inflation.

As stated elsewhere, the expansion of the credit is funded by consolidating it with the Earned Income Tax Credit, the deduction for children and limitations on or elimination of the mortgage interest and property tax deductions. The extension of this credit to non-workers is offset by abolishing supplemental retirement programs, such as Supplemental Nutrition Assistance and housing assistance.

Once the application process is complete, the Federal (or regional) government will distribute payments, as well as the expanded refundable Child Tax Credit for any dependent children, all of whom would qualify for Medicare, including any long term care provisions transferred to the federal government from the Medicaid program.

If vocational or educational training is required, as it likely should be in some cases, then the training provider will serve as both “case worker” and conduit for additional benefits, including the Child Tax Credit. Participants would be paid the minimum wage for engaging in training, along with any additional stipend provided to program beneficiaries of the benefit level were set higher.

Client health care would be funded by the federal government, but could conceivably be provided through the health care system provided to employees of the training provider. This is also our proposal for providing education to TANF beneficiaries. This care could take the form of health insurance or of staff medical personnel and facilities. In the event health care reform devolves into a public option or single payer system, the question of who pays for health care will be moot.

Clients who are incapable of completing training and finding employment will be transferred back to beneficiary status, with the training provider paying benefits during any transition period.

Program participants, like TANF participants, would not pay OASI payroll taxes, nor would program providers pay an employer contribution on their behalf or distribute any personal retirement account shares to them as an offset to their Net Business receipts taxes.

Unless they have significant outside income from an inheritance, tort judgment or lottery prize, it is doubtful that program participants will be hit with the Income and Inheritance Surtax. In any case, benefits and tax credits received would not be counted in determining adjusted gross income for this tax, although training stipends probably should be.

Program participation should not be means tested based on any judgment, although beneficiaries of significant inheritances should probably be excluded from the program, although that level should be set rather high – likely at the level where such benefits are taxed, currently proposed at $50,000 for individuals and $100,000 for joint filers and qualifying widow(er)s.

Thank you for this opportunity to share these ideas with the subcommittee. We are always available to discuss them further with members, staff and the general public.