Thursday, May 17, 2012

The Social Security Administration: Is it Meeting its Responsibilities to Save Taxpayer Dollars and Serve the Public?


Comments for the Record

United States Senate Committee on Finance
The Social Security Administration: Is it Meeting its Responsibilities to Save Taxpayer Dollars and Serve the Public?
Thursday, May 17, 2012, 10:00 AM
215 Dirksen Senate Office Building

By Michael Bindner
Center for Fiscal Equity


Chairman Baucus and Ranking Member Hatch, thank you for the opportunity to address this topic.  In our view, there are two ways of looking at this issue.  One is using the standard oversight model and the other is to look at whether things can be better.

Under the standard model, we need only ask whether costs are under control and whether benefit checks are delivered accurately and promptly.  If there were problems in this area, they would both be in the news and we would hear about them anecdotally from constituents and family members.  Aside from the odd mistake about being declared dead, which grabs headlines, the system is regarded as quite reliable.

The second question is more interesting.  How can the system be improved?  To some extent, the questions of saving taxpayer dollars and serving the public are contradictory.  Ending the entitlement to benefits for all who are eligible, or in some way limiting it, will certainly save taxpayer dollars, however that may not serve the public interest.  If the vast majority of beneficiaries are made worse off because inflation adjustments are less generous, this will be a drag on the economy and force more family support.  We find it hard to believe that this would be in the public interest. 

Neither would means testing benefits be seen in this light, as creating the perception that benefits are welfare will have some beneficiaries forgo benefits, even if they cannot afford to do so.  If excess benefits are paid to those who do not need them because of wealth, the best way to attack this problem is through the tax system, possibly by allowing wealthier beneficiaries to increase tax withholding to 100% and have the proceeds go toward the program rather than the general fund.

Any discussion of reform also leads to the question of personal accounts in Social Security.  Had the proposed solution of President Bush’s Commission to Save Social Security been enacted, the impact of the Great Recession on retirees would have been devastating, especially in the immediate aftermath of Congress yielding to popular pressure and voting against the TARP, which saw the largest one-day decline in wealthy in American history.  Oddly, many of those who would have been most affected would have been those who called for the TARP to fail.  Be that as it may, it was the perfect lesson on why the Bush proposals were unworkable.

The Center for Fiscal Equity, under its previous name, the Iowa Center for Fiscal Equity, submitted an alternative plan for personal accounts.  Unlike the Administration proposals, it would have muted the crash in two ways, had it been fully implemented in 2008.  While this itself is an impossibility, because full implementation takes decades, the possible effects on the future should not be discounted.  Under our plan, Old Age and Survivors Insurance revenues would not be diverted to Wall Street, but instead would be invested in the employee’s own workplace.  At full implementation, not only would most firms be employee-owned and therefore not in the market, but they would also take over most financial services for their employees, from mortgage finance to consumer loans.  In contrast to the securitization and speculation which caused the financial crisis of 2008, which we are still suffering from, Wall Street itself would have faded away and there would be no market for subprime mortgages, as there would be no subprime jobs.

The Center has updated its proposals from the Bush era and placed them in the context of comprehensive tax reform.  As you know, our reform occurs in four parts:

  •             A Value Added Tax (VAT) to fund domestic military spending and domestic discretionary spending with a rate between 10% and 13%, which makes sure very American pays something.
  •            Personal income surtaxes on joint and widowed filers with net annual incomes of $100,000 and single filers earning $50,000 per year to fund net interest payments, debt retirement and overseas and strategic military spending and other international spending, with graduated rates between 5% and 25% in either 5% or 10% increments.  Heirs would also pay taxes on distributions from estates, but not the assets themselves, with distributions from sales to a qualified ESOP continuing to be exempt.  
  •        Employee contributions to Old Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) with a lower income cap, which allows for lower payment levels to wealthier retirees without making bend points more progressive.
  •       A VAT-like Net Business Receipts Tax (NBRT), which is essentially a subtraction VAT with additional tax expenditures for family support,  health care and the private delivery of governmental services, to fund entitlement spending and replace income tax filing for most people (including people who file without paying), the corporate income tax, business tax filing through individual income taxes and the employer contribution to OASI, all payroll taxes for hospital insurance, disability insurance, unemployment insurance and survivors under age 60. 


One of the most oft-cited reforms for dealing with the long term deficit in Social Security is increasing the income cap to cover more income while increasing bend points in the calculation of benefits, the taxability of Social Security benefits or even means testing all benefits, in order to actually increase revenue rather than simply making the program more generous to higher income earners.  Lowering the income cap on employee contributions, while eliminating it from employer contributions and crediting the employer contribution equally removes the need for any kind of bend points at all, while the increased floor for filing the income surtax effectively removes this income from taxation.  Means testing all payments is not advisable given the movement of retirement income to defined contribution programs, which may collapse with the stock market – making some basic benefit essential to everyone.

Moving the majority of Old Age and Survivors Tax collection to a consumption tax, such as the NBRT, effectively expands the tax base to collect both wage and non-wage income while removing the cap from that income.  This allows for a lower tax rate than would otherwise be possible while also increasing the basic benefit so that Medicare Part B and Part D premiums may also be increased without decreasing the income to beneficiaries. 

If personal accounts are added to the system, a higher rate could be collected, however recent economic history shows that such investments are better made in insured employer voting stock rather than in unaccountable index funds, which give the Wall Street Quants too much power over the economy while further insulating ownership from management.  Too much separation gives CEOs a free hand to divert income from shareholders to their own compensation through cronyism in compensation committees, as well as giving them an incentive to cut labor costs more than the economy can sustain for purposes of consumption in order to realize even greater bonuses.  Employee-ownership ends the incentive to enact job-killing tax cuts on dividends and capital gains, which leads to an unsustainable demand for credit and money supply growth and eventually to economic collapse similar to the one most recently experienced.

As we wrote in the January 2003 issue of Labor and Corporate Governance, we would equalize the employer contribution based on average income rather than personal income. A major strength of Social Security is its income redistribution function. We suspect that much of the support for personal accounts is to subvert that function – so any proposal for such accounts must move redistribution to account accumulation by equalizing the employer contribution.

In the unlikely even that personal accounts find consensus, we propose directing personal account investments to employer voting stock, rather than an index funds or any fund managed by outside brokers. There are no Index Fund billionaires (except those who operate them). People become rich by owning and controlling their own companies. Additionally, keeping funds in-house is the cheapest option administratively. I suspect it is even cheaper than the Social Security system – which operates at a much lower administrative cost than any defined contribution plan in existence.

Safety is, of course, a concern with personal accounts. Rather than diversifying through investment, however, I propose diversifying through insurance. A portion of the employer stock purchased would be traded to an insurance fund holding shares from all such employers. Additionally, any personal retirement accounts shifted from employee payroll taxes or from payroll taxes from non-corporate employers would go to this fund.

The insurance fund will save as a safeguard against bad management. If a third of shares were held by the insurance fund than dissident employees holding 25.1% of the employee-held shares (16.7% of the total) could combine with the insurance fund held shares to fire management if the insurance fund agreed there was cause to do so. Such a fund would make sure no one loses money should their employer fail and would serve as a sword of Damocles’ to keep management in line. This is in contrast to the Cato/ PCSSS approach, which would continue the trend of management accountable to no one. The other part of my proposal that does so is representative voting by occupation on corporate boards, with either professional or union personnel providing such representation.

The suggestions made here are much less complicated than the current mix of proposals to change bend points and make OASI more of a needs based program. If the personal account provisions are adopted, there is no need to address the question of the retirement age. Workers will retire when their dividend income is adequate to meet their retirement income needs, with or even without a separate Social Security program.

No other proposal for personal retirement accounts is appropriate. Personal accounts should not be used to develop a new income stream for investment advisors and stock traders. It should certainly not result in more “trust fund socialism” with management that is accountable to no cause but short term gain. Such management often ignores the long-term interests of American workers and leaves CEOs both over-paid and unaccountable to anyone but themselves.

Progressives should not run away from proposals to enact personal accounts. If the proposals above are used as conditions for enactment, I suspect that they won’t have to. The investment sector will run away from them instead and will mobilize their constituency against them. Let us hope that by then workers become invested in the possibilities of reform.  Indeed, real reform is only possible if workers become more radicalized to the possibilities of workplace ownership and democracy.

The bargain struck in the Roosevelt era to allow capitalism to exist in exchange for moving workers into the middle class. As that bargain has been abandoned on one side, there is no reason for workers not to pick up old demands for workplace democracy. Indeed, it is essential that they do so in order to quit losing ground.

Social Security was part of a new social compact which, along with very high marginal tax rates and partnership with organized labor, built the middle class while keeping corporate capitalism in place. In a very real way, these programs were a reaction to not only the Great Depression, but a preventative to a very real movement toward more direct employee control and ownership of the workplace by the union movement. The passage of Taft-Hartley Act restrictions on concentrated ownership of the workplace were set in place as much to protect management from being swept away as they were a desire to diversify pension assets to protect workers.

This social context is important to understanding options for the future of Social Security.  In the early 1980s, Social Security was close to having to draw from the General Fund. Ronald Reagan’s conservatism was ascendant, with recently passed income tax cuts being phased in over a three year period and a beginning of the end of the bargain with the union movement to maintain labor peace in exchange for not pushing for a larger ownership share. Indeed, for all practical purposes, labor had become de-radicalized over time. It had moved to seeking to preserve benefit levels rather than advancing the interests of workers into the management suite.

In this context, a new grand bargain was created to save Social Security. Payroll taxes were increased to build up a Trust Fund for the retirement of the Baby Boom generation. The building of this allowed the government to use these revenues to finance current operations, allowing the President and his allies in Congress to honor their commitment to preserving the last increment of his signature tax cut, where the only other realistic option at the time was to abandon some or all of them, which was politically unacceptable given Republican control of the White House and the Senate.

Actions should be taken as soon as possible, especially when they must be phased in, as it is a truism that a little action early will have a larger impact later.

This trust fund is now coming due, with the expectation that shortfalls in Social Security payroll taxes will be covered by both income from interest income from the Social Security trust fund and eventually revenue from the general fund. The cash flow problem currently experienced by the Trust Fund is not the Trust Fund’s problem, but a problem for the Treasury to address, either through further borrowing – which will require a quick resolution to the debt limit extension or through higher taxes on those who received the lion’s share of the benefit’s from the tax cuts of 1981, 1986, 2001, 2003 and 2010. At some point, Congress must ignore the interests of its major donors (to both parties) and honor the bargain it made to shore up the trust fund. This is entirely appropriate, given the fact that much of the Trust Fund was built up in order to preserve the income tax cuts of 1981.

As luck would have it, adequate personal income tax increases to finance repaying the Trust Fund will occur automatically on January 1, 2013. This revenue profile, not current tax rates, must be considered the baseline on which any new bargain is formed.

The complication, and there are always complications, is that low tax rates enacted on capital gains, income and dividends during the Clinton and Bush administrations have created two asset based recessions, the first in the technology sector and the second in housing.

The recent recession is more accurately described as a Depression, since the financing of the real estate bubble has still not been resolved, even while economic growth numbers have begun to rebound. This new has both temporary and permanent effects on the trust fund’s cash flow. The temporary effect is a decline in revenue caused by a slower economy and the temporary cut in payroll tax rates to provide stimulus.

The permanent effect is the early retirement of many who had planned to work longer, but because of the recent recession and slow recovery, this cohort has decided to leave the labor force for good when their extended unemployment ran out. This cohort is the older 99ers who need some kind of income now. The combination of age discrimination and the ability to retire has led them to the decision to retire before they had planned to do so, which impacts the cash flow of the trust fund, but not the overall payout (as lower benefit levels offset the impact of the decision to retire early on their total retirement cost to the system).

It would be entirely inappropriate to renege on promises to the baby boomers to fund further income tax cuts by further extending the retirement age, cutting promised Medicare benefits or by enacting an across the board increase to the OASI payroll tax as a way to subsidize current spending or tax cuts. The current fiscal crisis should not be an excuse to use regressive Old Age and Survivors Insurance payroll taxes to subsidize continued tax cuts on the top 20% of wage earners who pay the majority of income taxes. Retirement on Social Security for those at the lowest levels is still inadequate. Any change to the program should, in time, allow a more comfortable standard of living in retirement.

The ultimate cause of the trust fund’s long term difficulties is not financial but demographic. Thus, the solution must also be demographic – both in terms of population size and income distribution. The largest demographic problem facing Social Security and the health care entitlements, Medicare and Medicaid, is the aging of the population. In the long term, the only solution for that aging is to provide a decent income for every family through more generous tax benefits.

The free market will not provide this support without such assistance, preferring instead to hire employees as cheaply as possible. Only an explicit subsidy for family size overcomes this market failure, leading to a reverse of the aging crisis.

The recommendations for raising net income are within the context of comprehensive tax reform, where the first 25-28 percent of personal income tax rates, the corporate income tax, unemployment insurance taxes, the Hospital Insurance payroll tax, the Disability Insurance payroll tax and the portion of the Survivors Insurance payroll tax funding survivors under the age of 60 have been subsumed by a Value Added Tax (VAT) and a Net Business Receipts Tax (where the net includes all value added, including wages and salaries).

Net income would be adjusted upward by the amount of the VAT percentage and an increased child tax credit of $500 per child per month. This credit would replace the earned income tax credit, the exemption for children, the current child tax credit, the mortgage interest deduction and the property tax deduction. This will lead employers to decrease base wages generally so that the average family with children and at an average income level would see no change in wage, while wages would go up for lower income families with more children and down for high income earners without children.

Gross income would be adjusted by the amount of tax withholding transferred from the employee to the employer, after first adjusting net income to reflect the amount of tax benefits lost due to the end of the home mortgage and property tax deductions.

This shift in tax benefits is entirely paid for and it would not decrease the support provided in the tax code to the housing sector – although it would change the mix of support provided because the need for larger housing is the largest expense faced by growing families. Indeed, this reform will likely increase support for the housing sector, as there is some doubt in the community of tax analysts as to whether the home mortgage deduction impacted the purchase of housing, including second homes, by wealthier taxpayers.

Within twenty years, a larger number of children born translates into more workers, who in another decade will attain levels of productivity large enough to reverse the demographic time bomb faced by Social Security in the long term.

Such an approach is superior to proposals to enact personal savings accounts as an addition to Social Security, as such accounts implicitly rely on profits from overseas labor to fund the dividends required to fill the hole caused by the aging crisis. This approach cannot succeed, however, as newly industrialized workers always develop into consumers who demand more income, leaving less for dividends to finance American retirements. The answer must come from solving the demographic problem at home, rather than relying on development abroad.

This proposal will also reduce the need for poor families to resort to abortion services in the event of an unplanned pregnancy. Indeed, if state governments were to follow suit in increasing child tax benefits as part of coordinated tax reform, most family planning activities would be to increase, rather than prevent, pregnancy. It is my hope that this fact is not lost on the Pro-Life Community, who should score support for this plan as an essential vote in maintaining a perfect pro-life voter rating.

Obviously, this proposal would remove both the mortgage interest deduction and the property tax deduction from the mix of proposals for decreasing tax rates while reducing the deficit. This effectively ends the notion that deficit finance can be attained in the short and medium term through tax reforms where the base is broadened and rates are reduced. The only alternatives left are a generalized tax increase (which is probably necessary to finance future health care needs) and allowing tax rates for high income individuals to return to the levels already programmed in the law as of January 1, 2013. In this regard, gridlock is the friend of deficit reduction. Should the President show a willingness to let all rates rise to these levels, there is literally no way to force him to accept anything other than higher rates for the wealthy.

Thank you for the opportunity to address the committee.  We are, of course, available for direct testimony or to answer questions by members and staff.

7 Comments:

Anonymous Joe The Economist said...

"Any discussion of reform also leads to the question of personal accounts in Social Security. Had the proposed solution of President Bush’s Commission to Save Social Security been enacted, the impact of the Great Recession on retirees would have been devastating"

In what way?

It would have taken years to create meaningful PSAs. Mind you the Bush Plan included guarantees so future retirees would have not been impacted. A future great recession would have devastating impacts on the government.

10:41 AM  
Anonymous Joe The Economist said...

"In the unlikely even that personal accounts find consensus, we propose directing personal account investments to employer voting stock, rather than an index funds or any fund managed by outside brokers."

You misunderstand market operations and the purpose of Social Security.

First, we aren't trying to make billionaires. The point of Social Security is to provide some supplemental income that will enable people to retire with some plan. The suggestion that we should concentrate investments at the expense of diversification is irresponsible. It isn't just asset concentration, you want to put retirement money in the company where you work. What are you going to do with people who work for Kodak?

Privatization is a flawed concept because there is nothing to privatize. According to SSA, Social Security is a 20.5 trillion dollar hole. I don't know how you privatize that.

10:47 AM  
Blogger Michael Bindner said...

The accounts that would have been accumulated would have lost value when the GOP followed Michele Bachmann into the insanity of voting against TARP. While some value has been gained back, the extreme volatility we have had since then is unacceptable. On the other hand, personal accounts holding shares in the employing firm would not have lost any value at all.

3:03 PM  
Blogger Michael Bindner said...

There is still a trust fund that can be distributed to either retirees or future retirees and additional revenue can be raised by switching from payroll to consumption taxes - with personal accounts to a VAT-like Net Business Receipts Tax (as suggested in the testimony).

3:04 PM  
Anonymous Joe The Economist said...

The Bush Plan was foolish not because of a 2009 implosion but the variation between investors would ensure sizable losses for the government.

It has been a while seen I have seen the Bush plan but I think it said something like 2% of wages would be diverted to a PSAs - phased in over time.

Even if you have 100% participation, you still don't have massive losses in 2009 UNLESS the person sells in the panic.

The concept of retirement insurance should focus on a dependable income stream. That means diversification and stock exposure. Since Social Security was founded the stock market has outperformed the Treasury investment by 50 to 1 and that goes through 70 years of bear markets.

Putting up retirement money in an employer doubles-up on risk because there is a correlation between employment and the safety of the retirement investment.

10:44 PM  
Anonymous Joe The Economist said...

The Trust is an accounting concept, a weigh station for future payments. According to the Social Security Administration the system contains $10 of promises for every $1 of asset.

Introducing a VAT doesn't change the math there, it is just throwing more taxbase at the problem. If I don't think that approach works it is because it diverts the taxbase away from debt control.

Ultimately, the younger generation sees that we put money into our retirement well leaving them with the cost of our government. I don't think that ends well.

10:51 PM  
Blogger Michael Bindner said...

Social Security's return is the entire economy, not the yield of T-bills, which is why a VAT-like Net Business Receipts Tax (with offsets for pesonal accounts) is entirely appropriate to fund it in a world economy. Most people who get rich do so not through diversification, which is a way to make investment managers rich, but by investing in their own companies. My plan would still have a third of the contribution to personal accounts go to an insurance fund which holds all similar employee-owned firms in the program - which both covers the contributions and provides a mechanism for the fund to take ovr the insured firm should a quarter of its employee shares object to how the firm is managed and investigation finds that something fishy is going on. This is the sword of Damocles that would keep most managers in line.

6:42 AM  

Post a Comment

<< Home