Friday, March 15, 2013
Comments for the Record
Committee on Ways and Means
Subcommittee on Health
Hearing on MPAC’s March Report to Congress
March 15, 2013, 9:30 AM
by Michael G. Bindner
The Center for Fiscal Equity
Chairman
Brady and Ranking Member McDermott, thank you for the opportunity to submit my
comments on this topic. As there has
been turn-over in the membership of the committee, we will largely repeat our
comments from last year, which provide real alternatives to current policy, as
well as current problems that no one is talking about relating to the
implementation of the Affordable Care Act.
We are always available to brief members and staff individually on our
comments or respond to any questions.
It is always important to
note that the whole purpose of social insurance is to prevent the imposition of
unearned costs and payment of unearned benefits by not only the beneficiaries,
but also their families. Cuts which
cause patients to pick up the slack favor richer patients, richer children and
grand children, patients with larger families and families whose parents and
grandparents are already deceased, given that the alternative is higher taxes
on each working member. Such cuts would
be an undue burden on poorer retirees without savings, poor families, small
families with fewer children or with surviving parents, grandparents and (to
add insult to injury) in-laws.
Recent
history shows what happens when benefit levels are cut too drastically. Prior to the passage of Medicare Part D, provider
cuts did take place in Medicare Advantage (as they have recently). Utilization went down until the act made
providers whole and went a bit too far the other way by adding bonuses (which
were reversed in the Affordable Care Act).
There is a middle ground and the Subcommittee’s job is to find it.
Resorting
to premium support, along with the repeal of the ACA, have been suggested to
save costs. Without the ACA pre-existing
condition reforms, mandates and insurance exchanges, however, premium support
will not work because people will have no assurance of affordable
coverage. This, of course, assumes that
private insurance survives the imposition of pre-existing condition reforms. We do not have to wait until implementation to
examine this question. Now that the
Supreme Court has spoken, the stock market will examine it for us. There may well be a demand for reform before
the election if the prospects for private insurance are found wanting. Conversely, if stock prices are maintained,
it is the market expecting mandates to be adequate.
Assuming mandates are seen
as inadequate, the questions of both premium support and the adequacy of
provider payments are moot, since if private insurance fails the only
alternatives are single-payer insurance and a pre-emptive repeal of mandates
and protections in favor of a subsidized public option. The funding of either single-payer or a
public option subsidy will dwarf the requirement to fund adequate provider
payments in Medicare and Medicaid.
Resorting
to single-payer catastrophic insurance with health savings accounts would not
work as advertised, as health care is not a normal good. People will obtain health care upon doctor
recommendations, regardless of their ability to pay. Providers will then shoulder the burden of
waiting for health savings account balances to accumulate – further encouraging
provider consolidation. Existing trends
toward provider consolidation will exacerbate these problems, because patients
will lack options once they are in a network, giving funders little option
other than paying up as demanded.
The
question of Accountable Care Organizations and cost sharing with payments is
also relevant. The Senate Finance
Committee addressed this question last year.
Hearing witnesses focused on Accountable Care Organizations and other
possible solutions to bend the cost curve.
This emphasis is all well and good of most beneficiaries of Medicare,
Medicaid and other forms of directly and indirectly subsidized insurance in
most years. Focusing on results is a
worthy goal for both patient well being and cost control, provided the patient
can be treated. Medicare, however,
devotes significant resources to the expensive care found in the last year of
life, which may involve multiple hospitalizations, full time nursing services
through Medicaid or a period of intensive care which ultimately proves
unsuccessful. In all of these
circumstances, particularly the last, unless we are willing to either have
doctors deny care or force survivors to pay bills that the government refuses
to pay, some form of fee for service is necessary.
In
April of 1998, our Principal’s father, Jim Bindner, had a heart attack, due in
part to either an undetected acute episode of diverticulitis (which was not
detected until autopsy) and in part to a lack of oxygen resulting from
successful radiation treatment for metastatic lung cancer. Had this attack occurred today, there is a
chance that advances in emergency medicine, including cooling of the patient,
might have resulted in a successful outcome.
This strategy, however, did not exist in 1998 and is still not widely
practiced. As a result, resuscitation
was incomplete and Mr. Bindner was left in a coma in intensive care for almost
a week before he passed.
The relevant question is,
what would a results based medicine scenario pay for in situations such as
this? Would the government have forced Mercy Medical
Center to simply eat the
costs? If so, would there have been
pressure from the hospital to end care sooner?
Would the alternative have been a copayment for these services for the
family?
Worse yet, would someone
have forced the choice on Mrs. Bindner to either agree to payment or
discontinue life support earlier to save cost?
These are the questions that such modalities as results based payment
bring forward loud and clear and they will hit every family with children of a
certain age. This is not the specter of
the death panel. It is something much
worse – a demand to agree to pay or make a tragic decision at the most
difficult time in anyone’s life.
Tragically, Mrs. Bindner
followed her husband in death last year one month after our last comments. We were not faced with a decision to
disconnect before we were ready, although we did withdraw support and allow her
to die in peace once it was confirmed there was no brain function. If it had been the choice of some insurance
bureaucrat rather than our choice, a tragic situation would have been made
worse.
While
some families could, of course, afford to pay for greater end of life services,
the prospect that money might by longer life, or a greater chance for
miraculous recovery to occur, would turn such care from what is now a right to
a commodity. The Center finds this unacceptable.
In
fee for service medicine, this choice is simply not required. Certainly the richest society on the planet
can afford to allow women facing imminent widowhood to avoid such heart
breaking choices if possible. Recent
reforms have essentially turned the Medicare Part A Payroll Tax into a virtual
consumption tax already by taxing non-wage income above $250,000 a year. It would be as easy to shift from a payroll
tax to a value added or VAT-like net business receipts tax (which allows for
offsets for employer provided care or insurance) and would likely raise
essentially the same amount of money, as most non-wage income actually goes to
individuals now liable for increased taxes.
If a VAT system is used, tax rates can be made lower because overseas
labor will essentially be taxed, leaving more income for American workers while
raising adequate revenue.
Premium
support systems would not have any impact at all on end of life care decisions,
except to the extent that they lead to cost cutting and the kind of choices
mentioned above that we can all hopefully agree are abhorrent. Ultimately, this negates much of the cost
savings that could come from premium support, so this idea should be dropped.
A
single-payer catastrophic plan would guarantee payment by the widow of any
difference between the catastrophic deductible and the accumulated health
savings account. This, again, is the
last thing any widow should have to face, even if the survivors have adequate
insurance.
Replacing
payroll taxes with Value Added Tax (VAT) funding will have no impact on whether
fee for service medicine at the end of life continues, except for the fact that
more adequate funding makes the need to save costs less urgent.
Shifting
to more public funding of health care in response to future events is neither
good nor bad. Rather, the success of
such funding depends upon its adequacy and its impact on the quality of care –
with inadequate funding and quality being related.
One form of increased
funding could very well be higher Part B and Part D premiums. This has been suggested by both the Fiscal
Commission and the Bipartisan
Policy Center . In order to accomplish this, however, a
higher base premium in Social Security would be necessary. Our proposal is that to do this, the employee
income cap on contributions should actually be lowered to decrease the
entitlement for richer retirees while the employer income cap is eliminated,
the employer and employee payroll taxes are decoupled and the employer
contribution credited equally to each employee at some average which takes in
all income. If a payroll tax is
abandoned in favor of some kind of consumption tax, all income, both wage and
non-wage, would be taxed and the tax rate may actually be lowered.
Ultimately,
fixing health care reform will require more funding, probably some kind of
employer payroll or net business receipts tax – which would also fund the
shortfall in Medicare and Medicaid (and take over most of their public revenue
funding), regardless of whether Part B and D premiums are adjusted. If the same consumption tax pays both
retirement income and government health plans, the impact on the taxpayer is
exactly nil in the long term.
We
will now move to an analysis of funding options and their impact on patient
care and cost control.
The
committee well understands the ins and outs of increasing the payroll tax, so we
will confine our remarks to a fuller explanation of Net Business Receipts Taxes
(NBRT). Its base is similar to a Value Added Tax (VAT), but not identical.
Unlike
a VAT, an NBRT would not be visible on receipts and should not be zero rated at
the border – nor should it be applied to imports. While both collect from
consumers, the unit of analysis for the NBRT should be the business rather than
the transaction. As such, its application should be universal – covering both
public companies who currently file business income taxes and private companies
who currently file their business expenses on individual returns.
The
key difference between the two taxes is that the NBRT should be the vehicle for
distributing tax benefits for families, particularly the Child Tax Credit, the
Dependent Care Credit and the Health Insurance Exclusion, as well as any
recently enacted credits or subsidies under the ACA. In the event the ACA is
reformed, any additional subsidies or taxes should be taken against this tax
(to pay for a public option or provide for catastrophic care and Health Savings
Accounts and/or Flexible Spending Accounts).
The NBRT can provide an
incentive for cost savings if we allow employers to offer services privately to
both employees and retirees in exchange for a substantial tax benefit, either
by providing insurance or hiring health care workers directly and building
their own facilities. Employers who fund catastrophic care or operate nursing
care facilities would get an even higher benefit, with the proviso that any
care so provided be superior to the care available through Medicaid. Making
employers responsible for most costs and for all cost savings allows them to
use some market power to get lower rates, but no so much that the free market
is destroyed.
This
proposal is probably the most promising way to arrest health care costs from
their current upward spiral – as employers who would be financially responsible
for this care through taxes would have a real incentive to limit spending in a
way that individual taxpayers simply do not have the means or incentive to
exercise. While not all employers would participate, those who do would
dramatically alter the market. In addition, a kind of beneficiary exchange
could be established so that participating employers might trade credits for
the funding of former employees who retired elsewhere, so that no one must pay
unduly for the medical costs of workers who spent the majority of their careers
in the service of other employers.
The
NBRT would replace disability insurance, hospital insurance, the corporate
income tax, business income taxation through the personal income tax and the
mid range of personal income tax collection, effectively lowering personal
income taxes by 25% in most brackets.
Note that collection of this
tax would lead to a reduction of gross wages, but not necessarily net wages –
although larger families would receive a large wage bump, while wealthier
families and childless families would likely receive a somewhat lower net wage
due to loss of some tax subsidies and because reductions in income to make up
for an increased tax benefit for families will likely be skewed to higher
incomes. For this reason, a higher minimum wage is necessary so that lower wage
workers are compensated with more than just their child tax benefits.
Adoption
of the NBRT does offer some interesting questions to the extent that offsets
are allowed. This shifts the ethical
locus from the government to employers, although the government would, of
course, require superior coverage to use any offsets. Still, the decision-makers on the ground
would not be someone at CMMS, but someone in the corporate benefits
office. While the practice of buying
life insurance for employees with the firm as beneficiary certainly mitigates
the cost, it might also appear ethically problematic if the payout encourages
the disconnection of support earlier than the family finds comfortable.
The form of the employer’s
company providing care in lieu of tax payment matters in this case. A firm with outside shareholders, even if it
is a model of compassion, will always be looked upon as potentially
untrustworthy in allocating end of life care, especially given their greater
incentive to do so to minimize costs which would otherwise go to profit. Employee-owned firms, however, might be
regarded as more trustworthy making these decisions, since employees would be
responsible to each other rather than to outside owners for cost
minimization. We believe such firms are
less likely to force hard end of life choices on widows, at least for financial
considerations.
As
we have stated previously, shifting the Old Age, Survivors and Disability
Insurance Employer Payroll Tax to a VAT-like Net Business Receipts Tax can
facilitate the accumulation of employee-owned shares, especially if a faster
transition which includes current retirees, who must be made whole (with some
of these transition funds being provided by the U.S. Treasury from the OASI
Trust Fund), will result in a lower NBRT levy immediately and in the
future. Converting retained equity to
employee-ownership may give some firms the opportunity to transition far
quicker than any other plan envisions.
These
proposals can solve the problem of rural health care as well. Provided employers don’t relocate (and more
employee-ownership makes this less likely), the infrastructure which provided
health care to workers would continue to exist for retirees. Employee-owned firms might also take on
sponsoring the training of doctors with the condition that they locate in rural
areas where they operate and have retirees.
In
a single payer or public option system, incentives can be paid to doctors who
move to rural areas. Of course, if we
simply expanded the Uniformed Public Health Service to a British style National
Health System, there is no issue of where doctors want to practice, they would
simply be assigned to the areas where they were needed.
Currently,
much in the way of rural health care comes from members of the Catholic Health
Association. In our previous example,
end of life care was provided in such a hospital in a rural area. As long as these hospitals continue to exist,
there will be some base of health care in rural areas – provided we as a nation
do not take advantage of their charity by cutting provider rates with the
expectation that they will always be a low cost provider or raise money to pick
up the slack. The Sisters who own and
run these hospitals have a retirement income crisis of their own, so
deliberately underpaying them is not a good long term strategy for assuring
rural health care exists in the long term.
Thank
you for the opportunity to address the committee. We are, of course, available for direct testimony
or to answer questions by members and staff.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home