Comments
for the Record
United
States House of Representatives
Committee
on Ways and Means
Health Subcommittee
Member
Day Hearing on
Legislation
to Improve and Sustain the Medicare Program
Wednesday, June 8, 2016, 2:00 PM
By
Michael G. Bindner
Center for Fiscal Equity
Chairman Tiberi and Ranking Member McDermott, thank you for the opportunity to
submit these comments for the record to the House Ways and Means Health Subcommittee
for the Member Day reviewing legislation currently being offered by members. These comments represent our current thinking
on Medicare reform, which was last provided to the Subcommittee in 2013 and that
reflect many of the proposals proposed by members. We will discuss the nature of social
insurance, premium support (including problems that no one is talking about
relating to the implementation of the Affordable Care Act), tax incentive
plans, accountable care organizations and end of life care in various funding
options, funding levels and Medicare premium increases, funding options through
tax reform and rural healthcare.
Social Insurance
It is always important to note that the whole purpose of
social insurance, including Medicare, is to prevent the imposition of unearned
costs and payment of unearned benefits for not only the beneficiaries, but also
their families. Cuts which cause
patients to pick up the slack favor richer patients, richer children and grandchildren,
patients with larger families and families whose parents and grandparents are
already deceased, given that the alternative is higher taxes on each working
member. Such cuts would be an undue
burden on poorer retirees without savings, poor families, small families with
fewer children or with surviving parents, grandparents and (to add insult to injury)
in-laws.
Recent history shows what happens when benefit levels are
cut too drastically. Prior to the
passage of Medicare Part D, provider cuts did take place in Medicare Advantage
(as they have recently). Utilization
went down until the act made providers whole and went a bit too far the other
way by adding bonuses (which were reversed in the Affordable Care Act). There is a middle ground and the
Subcommittee’s job is to find it.
Premium Support
Resorting to premium support, along with the repeal of
the ACA, have been suggested to save costs.
Without the ACA pre-existing condition reforms, mandates and insurance
exchanges, however, premium support will not work because people will have no
assurance of affordable coverage. This,
of course, assumes that private insurance survives the imposition of pre-existing
condition reforms. We do not have to
wait until implementation to examine this question. Now that the Supreme Court has spoken, the
stock market will examine it for us. At
this point in time, the market value of health insurance companies has not
declined, so the market indicates health care reform is working.
At some point in the future, insurance resistant
populations may reject mandates and start a downward spiral on coverage levels and
prices. If mandates are found to be
inadequate, the questions of both premium support and the adequacy of provider
payments are moot, since if private insurance fails the only alternatives are
single-payer insurance and a pre-emptive repeal of mandates and protections in
favor of a subsidized public option. The
funding of either single-payer or a public option subsidy will dwarf the
requirement to fund adequate provider payments in Medicare and Medicaid.
Tax Incentive Plans
Resorting to single-payer catastrophic insurance with
health savings accounts would not work as advertised, as health care is not a
normal good. People will obtain health care
upon doctor recommendations, regardless of their ability to pay. Providers will then shoulder the burden of
waiting for health savings account balances to accumulate – further encouraging
provider consolidation. Existing trends
toward provider consolidation will exacerbate these problems, because patients
will lack options once they are in a network, giving funders little option
other than paying up as demanded.
Accountable Care Organizations and End of
Life Care in Various Funding Options
The question of Accountable Care Organizations and cost
sharing with payments is also relevant.
The Senate Finance Committee addressed this question in 2012. Hearing witnesses focused on Accountable Care
Organizations and other possible solutions to bend the cost curve. This emphasis is all well and good of most
beneficiaries of Medicare, Medicaid and other forms of directly and indirectly
subsidized insurance in most years.
Focusing on results is a worthy goal for both patient well-being and
cost control, provided the patient can be treated. Medicare, however, devotes significant resources
to the expensive care found in the last year of life, which may involve
multiple hospitalizations, full time nursing services through Medicaid or a
period of intensive care which ultimately proves unsuccessful. In all of these circumstances, particularly
the last, unless we are willing to either have doctors deny care or force
survivors to pay bills that the government refuses to pay, some form of fee for
service is necessary.
In April of 1998, our Principal’s father, Jim Bindner,
had a heart attack, due to recent cancer treatment or an unidentified colon
condition. Had this attack occurred
today, there is a chance that advances in emergency medicine, including cooling
of the patient, might have resulted in a successful outcome. This strategy, however, did not exist in 1998
and is still not widely practiced. As a
result, resuscitation was incomplete and Mr. Bindner was left in a coma in
intensive care for almost a week before he passed.
The relevant question is, what would a results based
medicine scenario pay for in situations such as this? Would the government have forced Mercy
Medical Center to simply eat the costs?
If so, would there have been pressure from the hospital to end care
sooner? Would the alternative have been
a copayment for these services for the family?
Worse yet, would someone have forced the choice on Mrs.
Bindner to either agree to payment or discontinue life support earlier to save
cost? These are the questions that such
modalities as results based payment bring forward loud and clear and they will
hit every family with children of a certain age. This is not the specter of the death
panel. It is something much worse – a
demand to agree to pay or make a tragic decision at the most difficult time in
anyone’s life.
Tragically, Mrs. Bindner followed her husband in death due
to draught related foundation settling causing a gas leak in 2012. Her children were not faced with a decision
to disconnect before they were ready, although they did withdraw support and
allow her to die in peace once it was confirmed there was no brain
function. If it had been the choice of
some insurance bureaucrat rather than their choice, a tragic situation would
have been made worse.
While some families could, of course, afford to pay for
greater end of life services, the prospect that money might by longer life, or
a greater chance for miraculous recovery to occur, would turn such care from
what is now a right to a commodity. The
Center finds this unacceptable.
In fee for service medicine, this choice is simply not
required. Certainly the richest society
on the planet can afford to allow women facing imminent widowhood to avoid such
heart breaking choices if possible.
Recent reforms have essentially turned the Medicare Part A Payroll Tax
into a virtual consumption tax already by taxing non-wage income above $250,000
a year. It would be as easy to shift
from a payroll tax to a value added or VAT-like net business receipts tax
(which allows for offsets for employer provided care or insurance) and would
likely raise essentially the same amount of money, as most non-wage income
actually goes to individuals now liable for increased taxes. If a VAT system is used, tax rates can be
made lower because overseas labor will essentially be taxed, leaving more
income for American workers while raising adequate revenue.
Premium support systems would not have any impact at all
on end of life care decisions, except to the extent that they lead to cost
cutting and the kind of choices mentioned above that we can all hopefully agree
are abhorrent. Ultimately, this negates
much of the cost savings that could come from premium support, so this idea
should be dropped.
A single-payer catastrophic plan would guarantee payment
by the widow of any difference between the catastrophic deductible and the
accumulated health savings account.
This, again, is the last thing any widow should have to face, even if
the survivors have adequate insurance.
Replacing payroll taxes with Value Added Tax (VAT)
funding will have no impact on whether fee for service medicine at the end of
life continues, except for the fact that more adequate funding makes the need
to save costs less urgent.
Funding Levels and Premium Increases
Shifting to more public funding of health care in
response to future events is neither good nor bad. Rather, the success of such funding depends
upon its adequacy and its impact on the quality of care – with inadequate
funding and quality being related.
One form of increased funding could very well be higher
Part B and Part D premiums. This has
been suggested by both the Fiscal Commission and the Bipartisan Policy
Center. In order to accomplish this,
however, a higher base premium in Social Security would be necessary. Our proposal is that to do this, the employee
income cap on contributions should actually be lowered to decrease the
entitlement for richer retirees while the employer income cap is eliminated,
the employer and employee payroll taxes are decoupled and the employer contribution
credited equally to each employee at some average which takes in all
income. If a payroll tax is abandoned in
favor of some kind of consumption tax, all income, both wage and non-wage,
would be taxed and the tax rate may actually be lowered.
Ultimately, fixing health care reform will require more
funding, probably some kind of employer payroll or net business receipts tax –
which would also fund the shortfall in Medicare and Medicaid (and take over
most of their public revenue funding), regardless of whether Part B and D
premiums are adjusted. If the same
consumption tax pays both retirement income and government health plans, the
impact on the taxpayer is exactly nil in the long term.
Funding Options Through Tax Reform
We will now move to an analysis of funding options and
their impact on patient care and cost control.
The committee well understands the ins and outs of
increasing the payroll tax, so we will confine our remarks to a fuller
explanation of Net Business Receipts Taxes (NBRT). Its base is similar to a Subtraction
Value Added Tax (VAT).
Unlike a VAT, an NBRT would not be visible on receipts
and should not be zero rated at the border – nor should it be applied to
imports. While both collect from consumers, the unit of analysis for the NBRT
should be the business rather than the transaction. As such, its application
should be universal – covering both public companies who currently file
business income taxes and private companies who currently file their business
expenses on individual returns.
The key difference between the two taxes is that the NBRT
should be the vehicle for distributing tax benefits for families, particularly
the Child Tax Credit, the Dependent Care Credit and the Health Insurance
Exclusion, as well as any recently enacted credits or subsidies under the ACA.
In the event the ACA is reformed, any additional subsidies or taxes should be
taken against this tax (to pay for a public option or provide for catastrophic
care and Health Savings Accounts and/or Flexible Spending Accounts).
The NBRT can provide an incentive for cost savings if we
allow employers to offer services privately to both employees and retirees in
exchange for a substantial tax benefit, either by providing insurance or hiring
health care workers directly and building their own facilities. Employers who
fund catastrophic care or operate nursing care facilities would get an even
higher benefit, with the proviso that any care so provided be superior to the
care available through Medicaid. Making employers responsible for most costs and
for all cost savings allows them to use some market power to get lower rates,
but no so much that the free market is destroyed.
This proposal is probably the most promising way to
arrest health care costs from their current upward spiral – as employers who
would be financially responsible for this care through taxes would have a real
incentive to limit spending in a way that individual taxpayers simply do not
have the means or incentive to exercise. While not all employers would
participate, those who do would dramatically alter the market. In addition, a
kind of beneficiary exchange could be established so that participating
employers might trade credits for the funding of former employees who retired
elsewhere, so that no one must pay unduly for the medical costs of workers who
spent the majority of their careers in the service of other employers.
The NBRT would replace disability insurance, hospital
insurance, the corporate income tax, business income taxation through the
personal income tax and the mid-range of personal income tax collection,
effectively lowering personal income taxes by 25% in most brackets.
Note that collection of this tax would lead to a
reduction of gross wages, but not necessarily net wages – although larger
families would receive a large wage bump, while wealthier families and
childless families would likely receive a somewhat lower net wage due to loss
of some tax subsidies and because reductions in income to make up for an
increased tax benefit for families will likely be skewed to higher incomes. For
this reason, a higher minimum wage is necessary so that lower wage workers are
compensated with more than just their child tax benefits.
Adoption of the NBRT does offer some interesting
questions to the extent that offsets are allowed. This shifts the ethical locus from the
government to employers, although the government would, of course, require
superior coverage to use any offsets.
Still, the decision-makers on the ground would not be someone at CMMS,
but someone in the corporate benefits office.
While the practice of buying life insurance for employees with the firm
as beneficiary certainly mitigates the cost, it might also appear ethically
problematic if the payout encourages the disconnection of support earlier than
the family finds comfortable.
The form of the employer’s company providing care in lieu
of tax payment matters in this case. A
firm with outside shareholders, even if it is a model of compassion, will
always be looked upon as potentially untrustworthy in allocating end of life
care, especially given their greater incentive to do so to minimize costs which
would otherwise go to profit.
Employee-owned firms, however, might be regarded as more trustworthy
making these decisions, since employees would be responsible to each other
rather than to outside owners for cost minimization. We believe such firms are less likely to force
hard end of life choices on widows, at least for financial considerations.
As we have stated previously, shifting the Old Age,
Survivors and Disability Insurance Employer Payroll Tax to a VAT-like Net
Business Receipts Tax can facilitate the accumulation of employee-owned shares,
especially if a faster transition which includes current retirees, who must be
made whole (with some of these transition funds being provided by the U.S.
Treasury from the OASI Trust Fund), will result in a lower NBRT levy immediately
and in the future. Converting retained
equity to employee-ownership may give some firms the opportunity to transition
far quicker than any other plan envisions.
Rural Health Care
These proposals can solve the problem of rural health
care as well. Provided employers don’t
relocate (and more employee-ownership makes this less likely), the
infrastructure which provided health care to workers would continue to exist
for retirees. Employee-owned firms might
also take on sponsoring the training of doctors with the condition that they
locate in rural areas where they operate and have retirees.
In a single payer or public option system, incentives can
be paid to doctors who move to rural areas.
Of course, if we simply expanded the Uniformed Public Health Service to
a British-style National Health System, there is no issue of where doctors want
to practice, they would simply be assigned to the areas where they were needed.
Currently, much in the way of rural health care comes
from members of the Catholic Health Association. In our previous example, end of life care was
provided in such a hospital in a rural area.
As long as these hospitals continue to exist, there will be some base of
health care in rural areas – provided we as a nation do not take advantage of
their charity by cutting provider rates with the expectation that they will
always be a low cost provider or raise money to pick up the slack. The Sisters who own and run these hospitals
have a retirement income crisis of their own, so deliberately underpaying them
is not a good long term strategy for assuring rural health care exists in the
long term.
Thank you for the opportunity to address the committee.
We are, of course, available for direct testimony or to answer questions
by members and staff.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home