Comments for the Record
Senate Committee on Finance
Energy Tax Policy in 2016 and
Beyond
Tuesday, June 14, 2016
by Michael Bindner
The Center for Fiscal Equity
Chairman Hatch and Ranking Member Wyden, thank you for
the opportunity to submit our comments on this topic. Our comments are largely a restatement of
those provided in December of 2012 on the same topic, with updating as
appropriate. As usual, our comments are
based on our four-part tax reform plan, which is as follows:
- A
Value Added Tax (VAT) to fund domestic military spending and domestic
discretionary spending with a rate between 10% and 13%, which makes sure
very American pays something.
- Personal
income surtaxes on joint and widowed filers with net annual incomes of
$100,000 and single filers earning $50,000 per year to fund net interest
payments, debt retirement and overseas and strategic military spending and
other international spending, with graduated rates between 5% and 25% in
either 5% or 10% increments. Heirs would also pay taxes on
distributions from estates, but not the assets themselves, with
distributions from sales to a qualified ESOP continuing to be exempt.
- Employee
contributions to Old Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) with a lower
income cap, which allows for lower payment levels to wealthier retirees
without making bend points more progressive.
- A
VAT-like Net Business Receipts Tax (NBRT), essentially a subtraction VAT
with additional tax expenditures for family support, health care and
the private delivery of governmental services, to fund entitlement
spending and replace income tax filing for most people (including people
who file without paying), the corporate income tax, business tax filing
through individual income taxes and the employer contribution to OASI, all
payroll taxes for hospital insurance, disability insurance, unemployment
insurance and survivors under age sixty.
There are three aspects to
consider regarding whether energy policy should be conducted through the tax
code: energy taxes as transportation user fees; energy taxes as environmental
sin taxes and energy tax policies as a subsidy for business. How to design provisions for a sustainable
energy policy and tax reform will be discussed for each of these areas and we
will address certain oversight questions on whether current tax provisions have
been implemented efficiently and effectively.
Energy Taxes as Transportation User
Fees
The
most familiar energy tax is the excise tax on gasoline. It essentially functions as an automatic
toll, but without the requirement for toll booths. As such, it has the advantage of charging
greater tolls on less fuel efficient cars and lower tolls on more efficient
cars, all without requiring purchase of a EZ Pass or counting axles.
It
is a highly efficient tax in this regard, although its effectiveness is limited
because it has not kept pace with inflation.
This could be corrected by shifting it from a uniform excise to a
uniform percentage tax – however because the price of fuel varies by location,
there may be constitutional problems with doing so. The only other option to increase this tax in
order to overcome the nation’s infrastructure deficit – which is appropriately
funded with this tax – is to have the courage to increase it.
In
this time of high unemployment, such an increase would be a balm to economic
growth, as it would put people back to work.
Given the competitive nature of gas prices, there is some question as to
whether such an increase would produce a penny for penny increase in gasoline
prices. If the tax elasticity is more
inelastic than elastic, the tax will be absorbed in the purchase price and be a
levy on producers. If it is more
elastic, it will be a levy on users and will impact congestion (and thus
decrease air pollution and overall conservation). For many citizens, either prospect is a
win-win, given concerns over both climate change and energy industry
profits. The only real question is one
of the political courage to do what is necessary for American jobs and
infrastructure –and that seems to be a very open question.
Energy
taxes are currently levied through the private sector, rather than through toll
booth employees, which from the taxpayer point of view is a savings as it
externalizes the pension and benefit requirements associated with hiring such
workers.
In
the event that gasoline cars were replaced with electric cars, given either
improvements in battery charging technology or in providing continuous supply
through overhead wires, much in the same way that electric trains and busses
receive power, any excise per kilowatt for the maintenance of roads could be
collected in the same way – or the road system could be made part of a
consortium with energy providers, car makers and road construction and
maintenance contractors – effectively taking the government out of the loop
except when eminent domain issues arise (assuming you believe such a tool
should be used for private development, we at the Center believe that it should
not be).
The
electric option provides an alternative means to using natural gas, besides
creating a gas fuelling infrastructure, with natural gas power plants providing
a more efficient conduit than millions of internal combustion engines. The electric option allows for the quick
implementation of more futuristic fuels, like hydrogen, wind and even Helium3
fusion. Indeed, if private road
companies become dominant under such a model, a very real demand for
accelerated fusion research could arise, bypassing the current dependence on
governmental funding.
In
the event of comprehensive tax reform, the excise for fuel would be either a
component of or an addition to any broad based Value Added or VAT-like Net
Business Receipts Tax. The excise should
not disappear into such a general tax, as doing so would have the effect of
forcing all businesses to fund transportation on an equal percentage,
regardless of their use of such infrastructure.
Of course, like a VAT, any gasoline excise would be accounted for using
the credit receipt method, so that cascading taxes would not occur, as they do
now with this excise functioning as hidden levy.
Energy Taxes as Environmental Sin
Taxes
Carbon
Taxes, Cap and Trade and even the Gasoline Excise are effectively taxes on
pollution or perceived pollution and as such, carry the flavor of sin
taxes. As such, they put the government
in the position of discouraging vice while at the same time trying to benefit
from it. Our comments above as to
whether the tax elasticity of the gasoline excise has an impact on congestion
and pollution is applicable to this issue, although tax inelasticity will mute
the effect of discouraging “sinful” behavior and instead force producers to
internalize what would otherwise be considered externalities – provided of
course that the proceeds from these taxes are used to ameliorate problems of
both pollution (chest congestion) by paying for health care and traffic
congestion in building more roads and making more public transit available –
while funding energy research to ease the carbon footprint of modern
civilization.
Oddly
enough, this approach was once considered the conservative alternative to other
more intrusive measures proposed by liberals, like imposing pollution controls
on cars and factories or simply closing down source polluters. When those options are taken off the table,
however, or are considered impractical, then the concept of environmental sin
taxes becomes liberal and no action at all becomes the conservative position.
These
use of environmental sin taxes is by nature much more efficient economically
than pollution controls and probably also more efficient than allowing
producers and consumers to benefit from externalities like pollution,
congestion and asthma. As with transportation
funding, such taxes are only effective if they actually provide adequate
funding for amelioration or otherwise change consumer behavior. If the politics of the day prevent taxes from
actually accomplishing these objectives, then their effectiveness is
diminished.
The short term political win
of keeping taxes too low can only work for so long. Reality has a way of intruding, either
because infrastructure crumbles, congestion becomes too high, children become
ill with asthma (for full disclosure purposes, I suffered from this after
moving down-wind as a child from an Ohio Edison coal plant) and sea levels rise
– destroying vacation homes and the homes of those who support them – and if
Edgar Cayce is to be believed – the states that are the heart of the Republican
base.
The
role of energy taxes as sin taxes are preserved in comprehensive tax reform
only if they are preserved in addition to value added and net business receipts
taxes. If there is no separate tax or
higher rate for these activities, there is no sin tax effect and the “sin” is
effectively forgiven with any amelioration programs funded by the whole of
society rather than energy users.
Oddly
enough, because the Center does not mention carbon taxes or cap and trade in
our standard proposal, liberal commentators on Daily Kos criticize its lack and
assume we don’t believe in them at all.
This is far from the case, as our proposals say nothing about replacing
such taxes with our proposed VAT and NBRT.
Our proposal is to replace low and mid rate income taxes, corporate
income taxes and non-OASI payroll taxes with these revenues. We simply don’t touch the question of any
other excise. This shows how much the
fortunes of energy taxes have changed since Vice President Gore suggested their
inclusion in President Clinton’s tax proposals.
Energy Tax Policies as a Subsidy for
Business
There
are quite a few ways in which energy tax policy subsidizes business. The most basic way is the assessment of
adequate energy taxes, or taxes generally, to pay for government procurement of
infrastructure and research. If tax
reform does not include adequate revenue, the businesses which fulfill these
contracts will be forced to either reduce staff or go out of business. Government spending stimulates the economy
when more money is spent because taxes are raised and dedicated (or even
earmarked) for these uses. Eliminating specific energy taxes in tax reform
forces this work into competition with other government needs.
Let me be clear that the Center does not
propose such a move. Our approach
actually favors more, not less, identification of revenues with expenditures,
reducing their fungibility, with the expectation that taxes increase when needs
are greater and decrease when they are met, either through building in advance
of need or finding an alternative private means of providing government
services.
The
more relevant case to Committee’s question is the existence of research and
exploration subsidies as they exist inside of more general levies, such as the
Corporate Income Tax. To the extent to
which tax reform eliminates this tax and replaces it with reforms such as the
Net Business Receipts Tax (which taxes both labor and profit), such subsidies
are problematic, but not impossible to preserve.
This
is one of the virtues of a separate Net Business Receipts Tax, rather than
replacing the Corporate Income Tax with a VAT or a Fair Tax – which by their
nature have no offsetting tax expenditures.
The challenge arises, however, when the existence of such subsidies
carry with them the very justified impression that less well connected
industries must pay higher taxes in order to preserve these tax subsidies. Worse is the perception, which would arise
with their use in a business receipts tax,
that such subsidies effectively result in lower wages across the
economy. Such a perception, which has
some basis in reality, would be certain death for any subsidy.
One
must look deeper into the nature of these activities to determine whether a
subsidy is justified, or even possible.
If subsidized activities are purchased from another firm, the nature of
both a VAT and an NBRT alleviate the need for any subsidy at all, because the
VAT paid implicit in the fees for research and exploration would simply be passed
through to the next level on the supply chain and would be considered outside
expenditures for NBRT calculation and therefore not taxable. If research and exploration is conducted in
house, then the labor component of these activities would be taxed under both
the VAT and the NBRT, as they are currently taxed under personal income and
payroll taxes now.
The
only real issue is whether the profits or losses from these activities receive
special tax treatment. Because profit
and loss are not separately calculated under such taxes, which are essentially
consumption taxes, the answer must be no.
The ability to socialize losses and privatize profits through the NBRT
would cease to exist with the tax it is replacing.
If
society continues to value such subsidies, they would have to come as an offset
to a carbon tax or cap and trade regime, if at all, as the excise tax for
energy is essentially a retail sales tax and the industrial model under which
the energy industry operates insulates the gasoline excise from the application
of any research and exploration credits.
If the energy companies were to change their model to end independent
sales and distribution networks and treat all such franchisees as employees
(with the attendant risk of unionization), then the subject subsidies could be
preserved – provided that the related energy tax is increased so that the
subsidy could actually operate – favoring those who participate in research and
development and penalizing those who do not.
In
other words, if big oil wants to keep this subsidy when there are no corporate
income tax, it must buy up all its franchisees and allow the government to
double the gasoline tax with a deduction at payment for research and
exploration.
Without
taxes, there can be no subsidy.
The last subsidy issue
involves the use of a Value Added Tax as an oil import fee. If the VAT replaces some percentage of
current employee and investor income taxes, domestically produced energy
products become more competitive on the world market, provided that the VAT is
border adjustable, which it would be.
For example, if Alaska crude is shipped to Japan for refining and use or
western low-sulfur coal is shipped to China, it would be cheaper than the same
product shipped under today’s tax system.
The
NBRT would not be border adjustable because it is designed to pay for
entitlement costs which benefit employees and their families directly, so that
it is appropriate for the foreign beneficiaries of their labor to fund these
costs. Additionally, the ultimate goal
of enacting the NBRT is to include tax expenditures to encourage employers to
fund activities now provided by the government – from subsidies for children to
retiree health care to education to support for adult literacy. Allowing this tax to be zero-rated at the
border removes the incentive to use these subsidies, keeping government
services in business and requiring higher taxation to support the governmental
infrastructure to arrange these services – like the Committee on Finance.
Thank
you for this opportunity to share these ideas with the committee. As always, we are available to meet with
members and staff or to provide direct testimony on any topic you wish.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home